上海品茶

世界银行:批发电力市场设计:理论基础与选择(英文版)(53页).pdf

编号:125355  PDF  DOCX 53页 400.48KB 下载积分:VIP专享
下载报告请您先登录!

世界银行:批发电力市场设计:理论基础与选择(英文版)(53页).pdf

1、1 Wholesale Electricity Market Design by Frank A.Wolak Director,Program on Energy and Sustainable Development(PESD)Holbrook Working Professor of Commodity Price Studies Department of Economics Stanford University Stanford,CA 94305-6072 wolakzia.stanford.edu Current Draft:November 20,2019 2 Abstract

2、Wholesale electricity market design requires an explicit regulatory process to set the market rules for compensating and charging market participants for their actions.This has led to market designs tailored to the initial conditions in the industry and the political forces driving the restructuring

3、 process in that region.The experience of the past 25 years with wholesale market design has led to increasing standardization,particularly within the United States and within Europe.This paper identifies the key features of successful electricity market designs.These include:(1)the match between th

4、e short-term market used to dispatch generation units and the physical operation of electricity network,(2)effective regulatory and market mechanisms to ensure long-term generation resource adequacy,(3)appropriate mechanisms to mitigate local market power,and(4)mechanisms to allow the active involve

5、ment of final demand in the short-term market.This is followed by a discussion of how these lessons can be applied to developing countries and small markets,so that these regions can benefit from wholesale electricity competition at lower cost and with less administrative burden than larger markets.

6、Market design enhancements that support the cost effective integration of both grid-scale and distributed renewables is briefly discussed.The paper closes with proposed directions for future research in the area of electricity market design.1 1.IntroductionAlthough different jurisdictions around the

7、 world had different motivations for restructuring their electricity supply industries and introducing wholesale electricity markets,all had the goal of improving industry performance.Because electricity market design requires an explicit regulatory process to set the market rules,initial conditions

8、 in the industry and political factors can drive the choice of a jurisdictions initial market design.This choice can interfere with the ability of the subsequent regulatory process to improve industry performance and ultimately benefit electricity consumers.Particularly in the United States(US)and E

9、urope,there has been a convergence of market designs,although the standard market design in the US is quite different from the standard market design in Europe.This difference can be largely explained by differences in initial conditions and the political forces driving the restructuring process in

10、each region.However,the desire of many jurisdictions to scale the amount of intermittent wind and solar generation resources is creating new market design challenges that are likely to lead to greater convergence between the market designs in the US and Europe.International experience with more than

11、 twenty-five years of wholesale electricity market design has revealed several factors that are crucial to achieving lasting improvements in industry performance and tangible economic benefits to electricity consumers.These factors are:(1)the match between the short-term market used to set prices an

12、d dispatch generation units and how the actual electricity network is operated,(2)effective market and regulatory mechanisms to ensure long-term generation and transmission resource adequacy,(3)appropriate mechanisms to mitigate system-wide and local market power,and(4)mechanisms to allow active inv

13、olvement of final demand in the short-term market.As we discuss below,these factors must be addressed in any successful restructuring process because wholesale and retail market mechanisms decentralize many of the activities that formerly took place within the vertically-integrated monopoly.In addit

14、ion,at least during the initial stages of the restructured industry,there is a small number of wholesale and retail market participants,which implies that wholesale and retail market rules can significantly affect the behavior of market participants,often to the detriment of electricity consumers.Co

15、nsequently,designing wholesale and retail market rules requires accounting for the impact each market rule 2 has on the behavior of individual market participants.These market rules must create economic incentives for actions by individual wholesale and retail market participants that enhance,or at

16、least do not detract from,real-time system reliability or long-term supply adequacy.The market designer must recognize that any wholesale or retail market rule will be exploited by all market participants to enhance their ability to maximize profits from selling wholesale or retail electricity or mi

17、nimizing retail electricity procurement costs.The most successful re-structured markets are those with market rules that account for the self-interested behavior of all market participants.Much of this chapter is devoted to analysing each of the above-mentioned four factors determining the performan

18、ce of a restructured electricity supply industry from this perspective and using the lessons learned from international experience to provide recommendations for the design of a successful wholesale electricity market.The remainder of this chapter proceeds as follows.Section 2 first describes why el

19、ectricity requires an explicit market design process.Section 3 summarizes the factors leading to the different experiences with and outcomes of the wholesale market design process in the US versus Europe and other industrialized countries.Sections 4 to 7 present the four major lessons from internati

20、onal experience with wholesale market design.Section 4 outlines the importance of the match between network model used to operate the forward market used to set prices and dispatch levels and the physical network used to operate the electricity supply industry in real-time.This section argues that a

21、 multi-settlement locational marginal pricing wholesale market is likely to achieve the best possible match between how the transmission network operates and how the wholesale market determines prices and dispatch levels for any feasible configuration of the transmission network.Section 5,explains w

22、hy a liquid forward market for energy is likely to be the most efficient way to ensure both short-term and long-term resource adequacy.This section also discusses the properties of a capacity payment mechanism,an alternative approach to long-term resource adequacy.Section 6 describes why fixed-price

23、 long-term contracts are an effective mechanism for limiting the incentive of suppliers to exercise system-wide unilateral market power in the short-term market.This section also discusses local market power mitigation mechanisms,which exist in all US markets and most international markets,although

24、the details of these mechanisms differ across markets.Section 7 emphasizes the need for active involvement of final demand in the wholesale market,particularly in regions that have deployed hourly meters.1 A 1 In this chapter,I use the term hourly meter to refer to any meter than can record consumpt

25、ion in a fixed time interval such as 3 multi-settlement locational marginal pricing market is shown to provide the ideal platform for active participation of final demand.Section 8 builds on the discussion in Sections 4 to 7 to propose a market design for developing countries that is likely to captu

26、re the major source of benefits electricity industry restructuring while recognizing the regulatory and institutional challenges facing developing countries.This market design avoids many of the more costly features of formal wholesale electricity markets in the industrialized world with a significa

27、ntly reduced regulatory burden.This section also describes how this market design can be implemented in a small market with a vertically-integrated utility that purchases a portion of its electricity from independent power producers.Section 9 considers the question of what market design can successf

28、ully integrate a significant amount of intermittent renewable resources at both the transmission and distribution grid level.A number of countries have policies to increase the amount renewable energy they consume.I describe how a multi-settlement locational marginal pricing market with an energy co

29、ntracting based long-term resource adequacy mechanism can support the efficient deployment of intermittent renewable resources in both the transmission and distribution grids.2.WhyElectricityIsDifferentIt is difficult to conceive of an industry where introducing market mechanisms at the wholesale an

30、d retail level is more challenging for a policymaker.Virtually every aspect of the technology of electricity delivery and how it has been historically priced to final electricity consumers enhances the ability of suppliers to raise the prices they are paid through their unilateral actions,what is ty

31、pically referred to as exercising unilateral market power.Supply must equal demand at every instant in time and at each location in the transmission and distribution networks.If this does not occur then these networks can become unstable and brownouts and blackouts can occur.It is also very costly t

32、o store electricity.Constructing storage facilities typically requires substantial up-front investments and basic physics implies significantly more than 1 MWh of energy must be produced to store 1 MWh of energy.Production of electricity is subject to extreme capacity constraints in the sense that i

33、t is physically impossible to get more than a pre-specified amount of energy from a generation unit in an hour.These capacity constraints limit the size of every 15 minutes,half-hour or hour.4 the supply response by competitors to the attempts of a generation unit owner to raise the price it is paid

34、 for electricity.Finally,delivery of the product consumed must take place through a potentially congested,looped transmission network,and how transmission capacity is allocated to different market participants exerts an enormous influence on their behavior.Historically,how electricity has been price

35、d to final consumers makes wholesale demand extremely inelastic,if not perfectly inelastic,with respect to the hourly wholesale price.Customers are usually charged a single fixed price or according to a fixed nonlinear price schedule for each kilowatt-hour(KWh)they consume during the billing cycle,r

36、egardless of the value of the wholesale price when each KWh is consumed.Paying according to a fixed-retail price schedule implies that these customers have hourly demands with zero price elasticity with respect to the hourly wholesale price,which significantly enhances the ability of suppliers to ex

37、ercise unilateral market power in the short-term market.The requirement to deliver electricity to final electricity consumers through a specialized transmission and distribution network that is too expensive to duplicate for a given geographic area precludes the usual approach to finding a market de

38、sign that best meets the needs of consumers and producers.For most products,the market design process involves consumers deciding which products and locations to patronize and producers deciding which products and locations to serve.Some locations and products favor producers and others favor consum

39、ers.However,willing buyers and sellers of the same product at the same location is a necessary condition for trade to take place.Coffee retailing is a recent example of this process.Historically,a customer interested in purchasing a cup of coffee would go to a diner or convenience store.However,spec

40、ialized coffee retailers such as Starbucks and Peets entered and attracted customers and as a result many traditional coffee outlets lost customers.The customers lost by traditional coffee shops and diners and gained by specialized coffee retailers reduced the profitability and increased the likelih

41、ood of exit by the former and increased the financial viability of the latter.This dynamic is continually taking place in all markets where consumers and producers can vote with their feet for their preferred market design.This process of consumers and producers voting with their feet is not availab

42、le to the electricity supply industry because the product must be injected and delivered to final consumers through the same transmission and distribution network,and even in developing countries customers have limited tolerance for an interruption of their supply of electricity.Moreover,5 reliable

43、delivery of the electricity requires maintaining supply and demand balance at all locations in the grid at every instant in time.Consequently,any new supplier still delivers its electricity through this network and all customers still receive grid-supplied electricity from this network.As consequenc

44、e,the market design process must take place through explicit regulatory actions that set the rules for how market participants connect to the network and how they are paid for the electricity they inject and how they pay for the electricity they withdraw,rather than through the unilateral actions of

45、 producers and consumers of electricity.3.WholesaleMarketDesignintheUSandEurope The electricity supply industries in the US and Europe and other industrialized countries started from different initial conditions which also led to different political motivations for electricity industry restructuring

46、.Europe and other industrialized countries typically started with state-owned national or regional vertically-integrated monpolies.The primary public policy concern was that these state-owned entities were over-capitalized and inefficiently operated.The political motivation was that privatizing them

47、 and introducing competition would create stronger incentives for efficient operation.For example,in England and Wales,the Central Electricity Generating Board(CEGB)was the state-owned entity broken up and sold off by the Margaret Thatcher government to create three wholesale electricity suppliersNa

48、tional Power,PowerGen and Nuclear Electricand the National Grid Company that operated the transmission grid.The twelve Regional Electricity Companies(RECs)that sold retail electricity and operated local distribution networks in their service territory were also privatized.2 In the US,very few of the

49、 vertically-integrated utilities in the regions that introduced a wholesale electricity market were state-owned.The vast majority were shareholder-owned with their output prices set by state public utilities commissions for almost 100 years.Although far from perfect,this state-level regulatory proce

50、ss was significantly more effective at a squeezing out productive inefficiencies than the state-owned utility model in the Europe and other industrialized countries.As Joskow(1997)notes,the major motivation for restructuring in the US was that competition for wholesale electricity would cause more e

51、fficient new capacity investment decisions than the vertically-integrated regulated monopoly regime.According to Fabrizio,Rose and Wolfram(2007)there is also evidence that restructuring reduced operating costs.2 Vickers and Yarrow(1988)provide a comprehensive treatment of this process.6 In contrast

52、to the US,countries in Europe and other parts of the world had little experience with monopoly regulation given their history of state-ownership of the electricity supply industry.Consequently,when the restructuring process began,these jurisdictions found their electricity supply industries with sig

53、nificantly different initial conditions relative to their the privately-owned,state-regulated counterparts in the US.In particular,efforts by state regulators in the US to limit retail price increases in response to the run-up in fossil fuel prices in the late 1970s led to very little investment in

54、new transmission capacity until the early 2000s in the US.Load growth over this time period in most parts of the country was met through generation capacity additions near major load centers rather than through large new capacity investments distant from the load center served by new transmission ca

55、pacity.Consequently,the wholesale markets in the US began operation with significantly less modern transmission networks and less transmission capacity than their counterparts in Europe and other industrialized countries,where the state-owned electricity supply industry was able to make significant

56、investments in transmission capacity over this same time period.This difference in initial conditions eventually led to different wholesale market designs,despite the fact that most initial US wholesale market designs were very similar to those in Europe.The United Kingdom was the first European cou

57、ntry to restructure in the early 1990s and it chose a market design that assumed a transmission network where all generation units were equally effective at meeting demand at any location in England and Wales.Specifically,this market set a single national price for electricity each half-hour of the

58、day.The other early wholesale market in Europe,the Nord Pool,set potentially different prices in a small number of geographic zones in Norway and Sweden,two initial members of the Nord Pool,which later expanded to include Denmark and Finland and now allows energy trading in thirteen European countri

59、es.All of the European markets have evolved to zonal or single-zone pricing models where the day-ahead forward market clears at this level of spatial granularity.These markets determine market-wide or zonal generation and load schedules and market prices.This is followed by a re-dispatch process whe

60、re intra-zonal transmission constraints and other real-time operating constraints are managed by the system operator for that region or country.Virtually all of the US wholesale electricity markets began as a either a single-pricing-zone market,as was the case in the New England ISO,or a zonal marke

61、t,as was the case in the PJM Interconnection,New York ISO,California ISO and Electricity Reliability Council of Texas(ERCOT),that followed a similar design to this standard European market.These markets had a 7 day-ahead forward market where generation and load schedules and prices were determined a

62、t the zonal or single-pricing zone level.This was followed by a congestion management or re-dispatch process run by the system operator to produce final schedules that were physically feasible given the configuration of the transmission network.Starting with the PJM Interconnection in the Eastern US

63、,market operators found that the incidence and magnitude of transmission congestion was so large and the cost of managing it increasingly expensive so a market design with more spatial granularity pricing was adopted.This process led the PJM Interconnection to adopt a locational marginal pricing mar

64、ket design with a day-ahead forward market and real-time market,what is referred to as a multi-settlement locational marginal pricing market design.All of the other regions of the US had similar experiences with the operational challenges and cost of managing transmission congestion within the prici

65、ng zones in their single or multiple-zone-pricing markets.Each eventually implemented a multi-settlement locational marginal pricing market design with ERCOT being the last to do so in December of 2010.Because of their history of state-owned utilities and significantly greater investments in transmi

66、ssion capacity from the 1970s up to the start of the re-structuring process,the wholesale markets in Europe and most other industrialized countries have managed to maintain their zonal market designs.However,the costs of making final schedules physically feasible has grown significantly as the share

67、 of intermittent renewable energy in many European countries has grown.In 2017 in Germany these costs were over 1 billion Euros,in Great Britain they were more than 400 million Euros,in Spain they were over 80 million Euros,and in Italy they were approximately 50 million Euros.3 These costs have led

68、 number of European countries to consider adopting more granular approaches to pricing.4.MatchBetweenMarketMechanismandActualSystemOperationAn important lesson from electricity market design processes around the world is the extent to which the market mechanism used to dispatch and operate generatio

69、n units is consistent with how the grid is actually operated.As noted in the previous section,in the early stages of wholesale market design in the US,all of the regions attempted to operate wholesale markets that used simplified versions of the transmission network.The single zone or zonal markets

70、assumed infinite 3 See Figure of 90 of ENTSO-E(2018).8 transmission capacity between locations in the transmission grid or only recognized transmission constraints across large geographic regions.These simplifications of the transmission network configuration and other relevant operating constraints

71、 can create opportunities for market participants to increase their profits by taking advantage of the fact that in real time the actual configuration of the transmission network and other operating constraints must be respected.These markets set a single market-clearing price for a half-hour or hou

72、r for an entire country or large geographic region despite the fact that there were generation units with offer prices below the market-clearing price not producing electricity and units with offer prices above the market-clearing price producing electricity.This outcome occurs because of the locati

73、on of demand and available generation units within the region and the configuration of the transmission network prevents some of these low-offer-price units from producing electricity and requires some of the high-offer-price units to supply electricity.The former units are typically called“constrai

74、ned-off”units and the latter are called“constrained-on”or“must-run”units.A market design challenge arises because how generation units are compensated for being constrained-on or constrained-off impacts the offer prices they submit into wholesale energy market.For example,if generation units are pai

75、d their offer price for electricity when they are constrained-on and the units owner knows that it will be constrained-on,a profit-maximizing unit owner will submit an offer price far in excess of the variable cost of the unit and be paid that price for the incremental energy it supplies,which raise

76、s the total cost of electricity supplied to final consumers.A similar set of circumstances can arise for constrained-off generation units.Constrained-off generation units are usually paid the difference between the market-clearing price and their offer price for not supplying electricity that the un

77、its would have supplied if not for the configuration of the transmission network.This market rule creates an incentive for a profit-maximizing supplier that knows its unit will be constrained-off to submit the lowest possible offer price in order to receive the highest possible payment for being con

78、strained-off and raise the total cost of electricity supplied to final consumers.Bushnell,Hobbs and Wolak(2008)discuss this problem and the market efficiency consequences in the context of the initial zonal-pricing market in California.However,this outcome is not unique to industrialized country mar

79、kets.Wolak(2009)discusses these same issues in the context of the Colombian single-price market with the negative and positive reconciliations payment mechanism.9 The European approach to market design can be thought of as taking a different approach to addressing the need to match the network used

80、by the day-ahead and intra-day forward markets to set prices and dispatch levels and the actual transmission network.A zonal or single-zone pricing market design can address this requirement if there is sufficient investment in transmission capacity to make the actual network match for as many hours

81、 of the year as possible the network assumed in the forward markets used to set schedules and prices.For example,a single-zone pricing model can be viable market design if the transmission planning process commits to transmission investments that makes transmission congestion and the need for re-dis

82、patch of generation units sufficiently infrequent and unpredictable as to not impact the behaviour of generation unit owners.As noted in Wolak(2015),the wholesale electricity market for the province of Alberta in Canada sets a single price for the province and has adopted a transmission policy that

83、ensures sufficient transmission capacity to make this energy market assumption a reality for actual system operation for the vast majority of hours of the year.The wholesale market in Australia operates a zonal market based on state boundaries.Because most of the major load centers are on the easter

84、n coast of the country and the major generation units tend to be further inland near the coal and natural gas resources,historically there was a limited amount of intrazonal congestion.However,this situation is changing with the increasing amount of intermittent renewable generation capacity install

85、ed in the Australia market.4.1.LocationalMarginalPricing(LMP)Almost any difference between the market model used to set dispatch levels and market prices and the actual operation of the generation units needed to serve demand creates an opportunity for market participants to take actions that raise

86、their profits at the expense of overall market efficiency.Multi-settlement wholesale electricity markets that use locational marginal pricing(LMP),also referred to as nodal pricing,largely avoid these constrained-on and constrained-off problems,because all transmission constraints and other relevant

87、 operating constraints are respected in the process of determining dispatch levels and prices in the wholesale market.All LMP markets in the US co-optimize the procurement of energy and ancillary services.4 This means that all suppliers submit generation unit-specific willingness-to-supply schedules

88、 for 4 Ancillary services are composed of different operating reserves required by the system operator to maintain real-time supply and demand balance.For the California ISO market,these are composed of Regulation Up and Regulation Down Automatic 10 energy and any ancillary service the generation un

89、it is capable of providing.Large loads and load-serving entities submit their willingness-to-purchase energy schedules to the wholesale market operator.Locational prices for energy and ancillary services and dispatch levels and ancillary services commitments for generation units at each location in

90、the transmission network are determined by minimizing the as-offered costs of meeting the demand for energy and ancillary services at all locations in the transmission network subject to all network and other relevant operating constraints.No generation unit will be accepted to supply energy or an a

91、ncillary service if doing so would violate a transmission or other operating constraint.An important distinction between an LMP market design and the standard European market design is the centralized commitment of generation units to provide energy and ancillary services.European markets do not typ

92、ically require all generation units to submit energy offer curves into the day-ahead market and instead allow individual producers to make the commitment decisions for their generation units.A self-commitment market can result in higher cost generation units operating because of the differences amon

93、g producers in their assessment of the likely market price.Self-commitment markets also do not allow the simultaneous procurement of energy and ancillary services and instead rely on sequential procurement of ancillary services after energy schedules have been determined.As Oren(2001)demonstrates,se

94、quential clearing of energy and ancillary services markets increases the opportunities for generation unit owners to exercise unilateral market power in the ancillary services market,because they know that units committed to supply energy cannot compete in the subsequent ancillary services market.On

95、 contrast,LMP markets that co-optimize the procurement of energy and ancillary services ensure that each generation unit is used in the most cost-effective manner based on the energy and ancillary services offers of all generation units,not just those owned by a single market participant.Specificall

96、y,the opportunity cost of supplying any ancillary service a unit is capable of providing will be explicitly taken into account in deciding whether use the unit for that ancillary service.For example,if the market-clearing price of energy at that generation units location is$40/MWh and the units offe

97、r price for energy is$30/MWh and the units offer price for the only ancillary service the unit can supply is$5/MW,the unit will be accepted to supply the ancillary service only if the price is greater than or equal to$10/MW,because of the$10/MWh opportunity cost of energy for that unit.In contrast,s

98、elf-commitment markets such as those that exist in Generation Control(AGC)reserves,Spinning Reserves and Non-Spinning Reserve.11 Europe and other industrialized countries must rely on individual market participants to make the efficient choice between supplying energy or ancillary services from each

99、 generation unit.The LMP pricing process sets potentially different prices at all locations in the transmission network,depending the configuration of the transmission network and geographic location of demand and the availability of generation units.Because the configuration of the transmission net

100、work and the location of generation units and demands is taken into account in operating the market,only generation unit dispatch levels that are expected to feasible in real-time given the expected configuration of the transmission network will be accepted to serve demand and they will be paid a hi

101、gher or lower LMP than other units,depending whether the generation unit is in a generation-deficient or generation-rich region of the transmission network.The nodal price at each location is the increase in the minimized value of the“as-offered costs”objective function as a result of a one unit inc

102、rease in the amount of energy withdrawn at that location in the transmission network.The price of each ancillary service is defined as the increase in the optimized value of the objective function as a result of a one unit increase in the demand for that ancillary service.In most LMP markets,ancilla

103、ry services are procured at a coarser level of spatial granularity than energy.For example,energy is typically priced at the nodal level and ancillary services are priced over larger geographic regions.Bohn,Caramanis,and Schweppe(1984)provide an accessible discussion of the properties of the LMP mar

104、ket mechanism.Another strength of the LMP market design is the fact that other constraints that the system operator takes into account in operating the transmission network can also be accounted for in setting dispatch levels and locational prices.For example,suppose that reliability studies have sh

105、own that a minimum amount of energy must be produced by a group generation units located in a small region of the grid.This operating constraint can be built into the LMP market mechanism and reflected in the resulting LMPs.This property of the LMP markets is particularly relevant to the cost-effect

106、ive integration of a significant amount of intermittent renewable generation capacity in the transmission network.Additional reliability constraints may need to be formulated and incorporated into LMP market to account for the fact that this energy can quickly disappear and re-appear.An important le

107、sson from the US experience with LMP markets is that explicitly accounting for the configuration of the transmission network in determining dispatch levels both within and across regions can significantly increase the amount of trade that takes place between 12 the regions.Mansur and White(2012)dram

108、atically demonstrate this point by comparing the volume trade between regions of the eastern US before and after these regions were integrated into a single locational marginal pricing market that accounts for the configuration of the transmission network throughout the entire integrated region.Hour

109、ly energy flows between the two regions increased by almost 1,000 MWh immediately following the integration of the two regions into an LMP market.There was no change in the physical configuration of the transmission network for the two regions.This increase in energy flows was purely the result of i

110、ncorporating the two regions into a single LMP market that recognizes the configuration of the transmissions network for the two regions in dispatching generation units.4.2.MultiSettlementMarkets Multi-settlement nodal-pricing markets have been adopted by all US jurisdictions with a formal short-ter

111、m wholesale electricity market.A multi-settlement market has a day-ahead forward market that is run in advance of real-time system operation.Generation unit owners submit unit-level offer curves for each hour of the following day and electricity retailers submit demand curves for each hour of the fo

112、llowing day.The system operator then minimizes the as-offered cost to meet these demands simultaneously for all 24 hours of the following day subject to the anticipated configuration of the transmission network and other relevant operating constraints during all 24 hours of the following day.This gi

113、ves rise to LMPs and firm financial commitments to buy and sell electricity each hour of the following day for all generation unit and load locations.The day-ahead market typically allows generation unit owners to submit their start-up and no load cost offers as well energy offer curves and both of

114、these costs enter the objective function used to compute hourly generation schedules and locational marginal prices for all 24 hours of the following day.This logic implies that a generation unit will not be dispatched in the day-ahead market unless the combination of its start-up and no-load costs

115、and energy costs are part of the least cost solution to serving hourly demands for all 24 hours of the following day.As noted earlier,to the extent that generation unit owners submit start-up,no-load and energy offer curves that are representative of their actual costs,the total cost of committing a

116、nd dispatching the generation units that arise from this centralized unit commitment process is likely to be less than total commitment and dispatch costs that result from a self-commitment market,such as those that exist in Europe and other industrialized countries.The energy schedules that arise f

117、rom the day-ahead market do not require a generation unit to supply the amount sold or a load to consume the amount purchased in the day-ahead market.13 The only requirement is that any shortfall in a day-ahead commitment to supply energy must be purchased from the real-time market at that same loca

118、tion or any production greater than the day-ahead commitment is sold at the real-time price at that same location.For loads,the same logic applies.Additional consumption beyond the loads day-ahead purchase is paid for at the real-time price at that location and the surplus of a day-ahead purchase re

119、lative to actual consumption is sold at the real-time price at that location.In all US wholesale markets,real-time LMPs are determined from the real-time offer curves from all available generation units and dispatchable loads by minimizing the as-offered cost to meet real-time demand at all location

120、s in the control area taking into account the current configuration of the transmission network and other relevant operating constraints.This process gives rise to LMPs at all locations in the transmission network and actual hourly operating levels for all generation units.Real-time imbalances relat

121、ive to day-ahead schedules are cleared at these real-time prices.To understand how a two-settlement market works,suppose that a generation unit owner sells 50 MWh in the day-ahead market at$60/MWh.It receives a guaranteed$3,000 in revenues from this sale.However,if the generation unit owner fails to

122、 inject 50 MWh of energy into grid during that hour of the following day,it must purchase the energy it fails to inject at the real-time price at that location.Suppose that the real-time price at that location is$70/MWh and generator only injects 40/MWh of energy during the hour in question.In this

123、case,the unit owner must purchase the 10 MWh shortfall relative to its day-ahead schedule at$70/MWh.Consequently,the net revenues the generation unit owner earns from selling 50 MWh in the day-ahead market and only injecting 40/MWh is$2,300,the$3,000 of revenues earned in the day-ahead market less t

124、he$700 paid for the 10 MWh real-time deviation from the units day-ahead schedule.If a generation unit produces more output than its day-ahead schedule,then this incremental output is sold in the real-time market.For example,if the unit produced 55 MWh,then the additional 5 MWh beyond the unit owners

125、 day-ahead schedule is sold at the real-time price.By the same logic,a load-serving entity(what Europeans call a supplier)that buys 100 MWh in the day-ahead market but only withdraws 90 MWh in real-time,sells the 10 MWh not consumed at the real-time price.Alternatively,if the load-serving entity con

126、sumes 110 MWh,then the additional 10 MWh not purchased in the day-ahead market must be purchased at the real-time price.By this same logic,a multi-settlement nodal-pricing market is well-suited to countries that 14 do not have an extensive transmission network because it explicitly accounts for the

127、configuration on the actual transmission network in setting both day-ahead energy schedules and prices and real-time output levels and prices.This market design eliminates much of the need for ad hoc adjustments to generation unit output levels that can increase the total cost of wholesale electrici

128、ty to final consumers because of differences between the prices and schedules that the market mechanism sets and how the actual electricity network operates.Wolak(2011b)quantifies the magnitude of the economic benefits associated with the transition to nodal pricing from a zonal-pricing market that

129、was very similar to the standard market design in Europe and other industrialized countries.On April 1,2009 the California market transitioned to a multi-settlement nodal-pricing market design from a multi-settlement zonal-pricing market.Wolak(2011b)compares the hourly conditional means of the total

130、 amount of input fossil fuel energy in millions of BTUs,the total hourly variable cost of production from fossil fuel generation units,and the total hourly number of starts from fossil fuel units before versus after the implementation of nodal pricing controlling non-parametrically for the total hou

131、rly output of the fossil fuel units in California and the daily prices of the major input fossil fuels.Total hourly BTUs of fossil fuel energy consumed to produce electricity is 2.5 percent lower,the total hourly variable cost of production for fossil fuels units is 2.1 percent lower,and the total n

132、umber of hourly starts is 0.17 higher after the implementation of nodal pricing.This 2.1 percent cost reduction implies a roughly$105 million reduction in the total annual variable cost of producing fossil fuel energy in California associated with the introduction of nodal pricing.A multi-settlement

133、 LMP market design is also particularly well suited to managing a generation mix with a significant share of intermittent renewable resources.The additional operating constraints necessary for reliable system operation with an increased amount of renewable resources can easily be incorporated into t

134、he day-ahead and real-time market models.Therefore,the economic benefits from implementing a multi-settlement LMP market relative to market designs that do not model transmission and other operating constraint are likely to be greater the larger is the share of intermittent renewable resources.Conse

135、quently,any region with significant renewable energy goals is likely to realize significant economic benefits from implementing a multi-settlement LMP market.A multi-settlement LMP market also values the dispatchability of generation units even though it pays all resources at the same location in th

136、e grid the same price in the day-ahead and real-time markets.Suppose that a wind unit sells 50 MWh and a thermal resource sells 40 MWh 15 in the day-ahead market at$30/MWh.If in real-time not as much wind energy is produced,the dispatchable thermal unit must make up the difference.Suppose that the w

137、ind unit produces only 30 MWh,so that the thermal unit must produce an additional 20 MWh.Because of this wind generation shortfall,the real-time price is now$60/MWh.Under this scenario,the wind unit is paid an average price of$10/MWh=(50 MWh x$30/MWh 20 MWh x$60/MWh)/30 MWh for the 30 MWh it produce

138、s,whereas the dispatchable thermal unit is paid an average price of$40/MWh=(40 MWh x$30/MWh+20 MWh x$60/MWh)/60 MWh for the 60 MWh it produces.Similar logic applies to the case that the wind resource produces more than expected and the thermal resource reduces its output because the real-time price

139、is lower than the day-ahead price because of the unexpectedly large amount of wind energy is produced.For example,suppose the wind unit sells 30 MWh and the thermal resource sells 60 MWh in the day-ahead market at$30/MWh.However,in real-time there is significantly more wind,so the wind unit produces

140、 50 MWh at a real-time price of$10/MWh.Because of this low real-time price the thermal resource decides to produce 40 MWh and purchases the additional 20 MWh from its day-ahead energy schedule from the real-time market.The average price received by the wind unit is$22/MWh=(30 MWh x 30/MWh+20 MWh x 1

141、0 MWh)/50 MWh and the average price received the thermal unit is$40/MWh=(60 MWh x$30/MWh 20 MWh x$10/MWh)/40 MWh.Despite paying the same price to all energy in the day-ahead and real-time markets,a multi-settlement market pays a higher average price to the dispatchable generation unit for the energy

142、 it provides during the same hour as the wind unit.One complaint often leveled against LMP markets is that they increase the likelihood of political backlash from consumers because prices paid for wholesale electricity can differ significantly across locations within the same geographic region.For e

143、xample,customers in urban areas that primarily import electricity over congested transmission lines will pay more than customers located in generation-rich rural regions that export electricity to these regions.Because more customers live in urban areas than in rural regions,charging final consumers

144、 in urban areas a higher retail price to recover the LMP at their location may be politically challenging for the regulator to implement.Most regions with LMP pricing have addressed this issue by charging all customers in a state,region,or utility service territory a weighted average of the LMPs at

145、all load withdrawal points in the geographic region.In the above example,this implies charging the urban and rural customers the weighted average of the LMPs in urban and rural areas,where the weight assigned 16 to each price is the share of system load that is withdrawn at that location.Under this

146、scheme,generation units continue to be paid the LMP at their location,but all loads pay a geographically aggregated hourly-price.For example,in Singapore all generation units are paid the LMP at their location,but all loads are charged the Uniform Singapore Electricity Price(USEP),which is the quant

147、ity-weighted average of the half-hourly LMPs for all generation nodes in Singapore.This approach to pricing captures the reliability and operating efficiency benefits of an LMP market while addressing the equity concerns regulators often face with charging customers at different locations prices tha

148、t reflect the configuration of the transmission network.Tangers and Wolak(2018)present evidence that this market rule can result in more competitive behavior in the wholesale market by vertically-integrated suppliers with the ability exercise unilateral market power.5.MechanismstoEnsureLongTermResou

149、rceAdequacyWhy do wholesale electricity markets require a regulatory intervention to ensure long-term resource adequacy?Consumers want to be able to withdraw electricity from the network when they need it,just like other goods and services.But it is unclear why electricity is so fundamentally differ

150、ent from other products that it requires paying suppliers for production capacity to exist.For example,consumers want cars,but they do not pay for automobile assembly plants.They want point-to-point air travel,but they do not pay for airplanes.They want a loaf of bread,but do not pay for the existen

151、ce of a bakery.All of these industries are high fixed cost,relatively low marginal cost production processes,similar to electricity supply.Nevertheless,all of these firms earn their return on capital invested by selling the good that consumers want at a price above the variable cost of producing it.

152、Clearly cars,air travel,and bread are in many ways essential commodities,yet there is no regulatory invention that ensures that there is sufficient production capacity for these products to meet demand.So what is different about electricity markets that necessitates the need for a long-term resource

153、 adequacy mechanism?The answer lies in how short-term markets for these products operate relative to that for wholesale electricity.This difference is the result of the regulatory history of the electricity supply industry and the technology of electricity metering.The limitation on the level of sho

154、rt-term prices and the way that supply shortfalls are dealt with in wholesale electricity markets creates what Wolak(2013)has been termed a reliability externality that requires a regulatory intervention to internalize.17 In the market for automobiles,air travel,and even bread,there is no explicit p

155、rohibition on the short-term price of the good rising to the level necessary to clear the market.Take the example of air travel.Airlines adjust the prices for seats on a flight over time in an attempt to ensure that the number of customers traveling on that flight equals the number of seats flying.T

156、his can result in very different prices for a seat on the same flight,depending on when the customer purchases the seat.A customer that waits too long to purchase a seat faces the risk of an infinite price in the sense that all of the seats on the flight are sold out.This ability to use price to all

157、ocate the available seats is also what allows the airline the flexibility to recover its total production costs.Airlines can set low prices to fill flights with low demand and extremely high prices on other flights,or at other times for the same flight,when demand is high.The ability to use the shor

158、t-term price to manage the supply and demand balance in the electricity supply industry is limited first by the fact that all North American wholesale electricity markets have offer caps that limit a suppliers offer price into the wholesale market and/or a price cap that limits the magnitude of the

159、eventual market-clearing price.In addition,historically virtually all electricity supply industries did not have hourly meters that can record a customers consumption during each hour of the month.Even today,most regions only have mechanical meters that compute the customers consumption for the enti

160、re month as the difference between two consecutive meter readings.With monthly or bi-monthly reading of mechanical meters,it is impossible for the utility to know how much electricity a customer consumed within a given hour of the month.5 Although these offer caps and price caps can limit the abilit

161、y of suppliers to exercise unilateral market power in the short-term energy market,they also reduce the revenues suppliers can receive during scarcity conditions.This is often referred to as the missing money problem for generation unit owners.However,this missing money problem is only a symptom of

162、the existence of the reliability externality,it not the cause.This externality exists because offer caps limit the potential downside to electricity retailers and large consumers(able to purchase from the short-term market)delaying their purchases of electricity until real-time operation.Specificall

163、y,if the retailer or large consumer knows the price cap on the short-term market is$250/MWh,then it is unlikely to be willing to pay more than that 5 Many regions have eliminated or are eliminating this technological barrier to allowing price to manage the real-time supply and demand balance by inst

164、alling interval meters for all customers and offering real-time meter reading as a regulated service.18 for electricity in any earlier forward market.This creates the possibility that real-time system conditions can occur where the amount of electricity demanded at or below the offer cap is less tha

165、n the amount suppliers are willing to offer at or below the offer cap.This outcome implies that the system operator must be forced to either abandon the market mechanism or curtail load until the available supply offered at or below the offer cap equals the reduced level of demand,as was the case a

166、number of times during the period January 2001 and March 2001 in California.Because random curtailments of supply-also known as rolling blackouts-are used to make demand equal to the available supply at or below the bid cap under these system conditions,this mechanism creates an“externality”because

167、no retailer or large consumer bears the full cost of failing to procure adequate amounts of energy in advance of delivery.A retailer that has purchased sufficient supply in the forward market to meet its real-time energy demand is equally likely to be randomly curtailed as the same size retailer tha

168、t has not procured adequate amounts of energy in the forward market.For this reason,all retailers and large loads have an incentive to under-procure their expected energy needs in the forward market.Particularly for markets with very low offer caps,retailers have little incentive to engage in suffic

169、ient fixed-price forward contracting with generation unit owners to ensure a reliable supply of electricity for all possible realizations of future real-time demand.For example,a 200 MW generation unit owner that expects to run 100 hours during the year with a variable cost of$80/MWh would be willin

170、g to sign a fixed-price forward contract to provide up to 200 MWh of energy for up to 100 hours of the year to a retailer.Because this generation unit owner is essentially selling its expected annual output to the retailer,it would want a$/MWh price that at least exceeds its average total cost of su

171、pplying energy during that year.This price can be significantly above the average price in the short-term wholesale market during the hours that this generation unit operates because of the offer cap on the short-term market and other market power mitigation mechanisms.This fact implies that the ret

172、ailer would find it expected profit-maximizing not to sign the forward contract that allows the generation unit owner full cost recovery but instead wait until the short-term market to purchase the necessary energy at prices that are limited by the offer cap.Although this incentive for retailers to

173、rely on a price-capped short-term market is most likely to impact generation units that run infrequently,if the level of demand relative to the amount of available supply is sufficiently large,it can even impact intermediate and baseload units.Because of the expectation of very low prices in the sho

174、rt-term market and the limited prospect of 19 very high prices because of offer caps,retailers may decide not to sign fixed-price forward contracts with these generation unit owners and purchase their energy in the short-term market.By this logic,a short-term energy market with an offer cap always c

175、reates an incentive for retailers to delay purchasing some of their energy needs until real-time,when these caps can be used to obtain this energy at a lower price than the supplier would be willing to sell it in the forward market.The lower the offer cap,the greater is the likelihood that the retai

176、ler will delay their electricity purchases to the short-term market.Delaying more purchases to the short-term market increases the likelihood of the event that insufficient supply will offer into the short-term market at or below the offer cap to meet demand.If a retailer knows that part of the cost

177、 of its failure to purchase sufficient fixed-price forward contracts will be borne by other retailers and large consumers because of random curtailment,then it has an incentive to engage in less fixed-price forward contracts than it would in a world where all customers had hourly meters and all cust

178、omers could be charged hourly prices high enough to cause them to reduce their demand to equal the amount of supply available at that price.Because externalities are generally caused by a missing market,another way of characterizing this reliability externality as a missing market for long-term cont

179、racts for energy.In this case,because retailers do not bear the full cost of failing to procure sufficient energy to meet their real-time needs in the future,there is a missing market for long-term contracts for long enough delivery horizons into the future to allow new generation units to be financ

180、ed and constructed to serve demand under all possible future conditions in the short-term market.The above discussion implies that unless the regulator is willing to eliminate or substantially increase the offer cap on the short-term market so that the short-term price can be used to equate availabl

181、e supply to demand under all possible future short-term market conditions,some form of regulatory intervention is necessary to internalize the resulting reliability externality.However,if customers do not have hourly meters that can record their consumption during each hour the billing cycle,they ha

182、ve a limited ability to benefit from shifting their consumption away from high-priced hours,so raising or having no offer cap on the short-term market would not be advisable.As the above discussion makes clear,relying on a capped short-term energy market price to ensure long-term resource adequacy d

183、oes not address the reliability externality and leaves both a missing money and missing market problem.Capacity payment mechanisms are one 20 approach to addressing this reliability externality designed primarily for thermal generation-dominated markets,where the major concern is insufficient genera

184、tion capacity to meet future demand peaks.In intermittent renewable dominated markets the major reliability concern is more likely to be insufficient renewable energy(i.e.wind and sunshine)to meet a sustained demand for energy,which implies other approaches to addressing the reliability externality

185、may dominate a capacity-based approach for these electricity markets.As the share of intermittent renewable generation in a wholesale electricity market increases,the magnitude of the reliability externality is also likely to increase.The uncertain availability of wind and solar resources increases

186、magnitude and duration of potential future energy supply shortfalls that must be managed,which implies many more instances when a capped short-term energy market may not yield a sufficient energy supply increase or demand decrease to maintain real-time supply and demand balance.Two general approache

187、s have been developed to address this reliability externality.The first is based on fixed-price and fixed-quantity long-term contracts for energy signed between generation unit owners and load-serving entities at various horizons to delivery.The second approach is a regulator-mandated capacity payme

188、nt mechanism.Typically,the regulator requires that load-serving entities purchase sufficient firm generation capacity,a magnitude defined by the regulator,to cover their annual peak demand.Generation unit owners receive a regulator-determined payment for the capacity they provide to the load-serving

189、 entity.Differing degrees of regulatory invention are used to determine this$/KW-year payment across the existing capacity payment mechanisms.5.1.FixedPriceForwardContractApproachtoLongTermResourceAdequacy The fixed-price forward contract solution is the standard approach used to ensure a real-time

190、supply and demand balance in markets for products with high fixed costs of production.The prospect of a high real-time price for the product provides incentives for customers to hedge this real-time price risk through a fixed-price forward contract.A supplier benefits from signing such a contract be

191、cause it has greater quantity and revenue certainty as result.The airline industry is familiar example of this phenomenon.There is a substantial fixed cost associated with operating a flight between a given origin and destination pair.Regardless of how many passengers board the flight,the airplane,p

192、ilot and co-pilot,flight attendants and fuel must be paid for.Moreover,there is a finite number of seats on the flight,so passengers wanting 21 to travel face the risk that if they show up at the airport one hour before the flight and attempt to purchase a ticket,they may find that it is sold out or

193、 tickets are extremely expensive because of the high real-time demand for seats.Customers hedge this short-term price risk by purchasing their tickets in advance,which is a fixed-price,fixed-quantity(one seat)forward contract for travel on the flight.These forward market purchases allow the airline

194、to better plan the types of aircraft and flight staff it will use to serve each route and how much fuel is needed for each the flight.Similar arguments apply to wholesale electricity markets to the extent that real-time prices can rise to very high levels.For example,in Australia the offer cap on th

195、e short-term market is currently 14,500 Australia dollars($AU)per megawatt-hour(MWh),yet annual average wholesale prices are less than$AU 100/MWh.The potential for short-term prices at or near the price cap provides a very strong incentive for electricity retailers and large customers to purchase th

196、eir electricity through fixed-price forward contracts,rather than face the risk of these extreme short-term prices.However,even at this level of the offer cap on the short-term market in Australia there have been a small number of half-hour periods when supply shortfalls occur,consistent with the re

197、liability externality argument.Purchasing fixed-price and fixed-quantity forward contracts far enough in advance of delivery for new entrants to compete to provide this energy ensures that retailers will receive a competitive forward market price for their purchase.These forward market purchases far

198、 in advance of delivery also ensure that the seller of the contract has sufficient time to construct the new generation capacity needed to meet the demand purchased through fixed-price forward contracts.Consequently,in the same sense that fixed-price forward contracts for air travel allow an airline

199、 to better match airplanes and flight staff to routes,fixed-price forward contracts for electricity allow generation unit owners to choose the least cost mix of capacity to serve the demand that has purchased fixed-price forward contracts for energy.Key to the success of this strategy for obtaining

200、sufficient generation capacity to meet future demand is the threat of very high short-term prices which provides the incentive for load-serving entities to sign fixed-price forward contracts for their expected future demands far enough in advance of delivery to allow new entrants to compete with exi

201、sting generation unit owners in the provision of these forward contracts for energy.However,most regions with restructured electricity markets are unwilling to allow short-term prices to rise to the level allowed in Australia.For example,all US markets except the Electricity Reliability Council of T

202、exas(ERCOT)have caps on the offer price that suppliers can submit at$1,000/MWh.ERCOTs offer cap is currently 22$9,000/MWh,which very close to Australias offer cap in US dollars.Again this level of the offer cap significantly limits the likelihood of supply shortfalls in the real-time market.Many who

203、lesale electricity markets outside of the US,particularly those in the developing countries,have offer caps far below$1,000/MWh.Low offer caps do not to create a strong enough incentive for load-serving entities to purchase enough fixed-price forward contracts far enough in advance of delivery to en

204、sure sufficient generation capacity to meet future demand.Consequently,in a number of Latin American countries,there are regulator-mandated requirements for load-serving entities to purchase certain percentages of their final demand in fixed-price forward contracts in advance of delivery.For example

205、,90 percent of forecast demand one year in advance,85 percent two years in advance and so forth.This regulatory mandate provides sufficient demand for long-term contracts far enough in advance of delivery to ensure enough generation capacity to meet future demand.It is important to emphasize that ma

206、ndating these contracting levels is unlikely to impose a financial hardship on retailers that lose customers to competing retailers.If a retailer purchased more fixed-price forward contract coverage than it ultimately needs because it lost customers to a competitor,it can sell this obligation in the

207、 secondary market.Unless the market demand for energy in the future is unexpectedly low,this retailer is just as likely to make a profit on this sale as it is to make a loss,because one of the retailers that gained customers needs forward contracts to meet its regulatory requirements for coverage of

208、 its final demand.Only in the very unlikely case that the aggregate amount of forward contracts purchased is greater than the realized final demand for the entire market will there be a potential for stranded forward contracts held by retailers that lose customers.Fixed-price forward contract obliga

209、tions also significantly limit the incentive of generation unit owners to exercise unilateral market power in the short-term market.To understand this logic,let PC equal the fixed price at which the generation unit owner agrees to sell energy to an electricity retailer in a forward contract and QC e

210、qual to the agreed upon quantity of energy sold.This contract is negotiated in advance of the date that the generation unit owner will supply the energy,so the value of PC and QC are predetermined from the perspective of behavior in the short-term wholesale market.Wolak(2000)demonstrates that the qu

211、antity of fixed-price forward contract obligations held by the generation unit owner determines what short-term market price the firm finds ex post profit-maximizing given its marginal cost of producing energy,the supply offers of its competitors,23 and the level of aggregate demand.Incorporating th

212、e payment stream a generation unit owner receives from its forward contract obligations,its variable profit function for a given hour of the day is:(PS)=(PC C)QC+(QS QC)(PS C)(1)where QS is the quantity of energy sold in the short-term market and produced by the generation unit owner,PS is the price

213、 of energy sold in the short-term market and C is the suppliers marginal cost of producing electricity,which for simplicity is assumed to be constant.The first term in(1)is the variable profit from the forward contract sales and the second term is the additional profit or loss from selling more or l

214、ess energy in the short-term market than the generation unit owners forward contract quantity.Because the forward contract price and quantity are negotiated in advance of the delivery date,the first term,(PC C)QC,is a fixed profit stream to the generation unit owner before it offers into the short-t

215、erm market.The second term depends on the price in the short-term market,but in a way that can significantly limit the incentive for the generation unit owner to raise prices in the short-term market.For example,if the generation unit owner attempts to raise prices by withholding output,it could end

216、 up selling less in the short-term market than its forward contract quantity(QC QS),and if the resulting market-clearing price is greater than the firms marginal cost(PS C),the second term in(1)will be negative.Consequently,only in the case that the generation unit owner is confident it will produce

217、 more than its forward contract quantity in the short-term market does it have an incentive to withhold output in order to raise short-term prices.The quantity of forward contract obligations held by a firms competitors also limits its incentive to exercise unilateral market power in the short-term

218、market.If a producer knows that all of its competitors have substantial fixed-price forward contract obligations,then this producer knows these firms will submit offer curves into the short-term market close to their marginal cost curves.Therefore,attempts by this generation unit owner to raise pric

219、es in the short-term market by withholding output are likely to be unsuccessful because of the aggressiveness of the offers into the short-term market by its competitors with substantial fixed-price forward contract obligations limits the price increase a producer can expect from these actions.This

220、dynamic creates the following virtuous cycle of forward contracting.If a producer knows all of its competitors have a substantial amount of their expected energy sales covered by fixed-price forward contracts,then it has an incentive to sign fixed-price forward to contracts for a substantial fractio

221、n of its expected energy sales.When all generation unit owners have a 24 substantial fraction of their expected energy sales covered by fixed-price forward contracts,then all of them have a common interest in reducing the cost of meeting these fixed-price forward contract obligations.The resulting r

222、eductions in the short term prices from more competitive behavior in the short-term market caused by high levels of fixed price forward contract coverage of final demand creates another virtuous cycle from fixed-price forward contracts.Generation unit owners that have sold forward contracts have a s

223、trong incentive to make the cost of supplying these contracts as low as possible.This should result in low short-term prices for energy,which will then be factored into subsequent negotiations for next round of fixed-price forward contracts.This dynamic for reducing short-term wholesale prices resul

224、ts from a persistent high level of coverage of final demand by fixed-price forward contracts that creates the incentive for all generation unit owners to reduce the cost of meeting their forward contract obligations.5.2.TheCapacityPaymentApproachtoLongTermResourceAdequacyParticularly in the US,capac

225、ity payment mechanisms appear to be a holdover from the vertically-integrated regulated regime with regional power pools where capacity payments compensated generation units for their capital costs,because the regulated power pool typically only paid unit owners their variable operating costs for th

226、e electricity they produced.Therefore,all fixed costs had to be recovered through other mechanisms besides the sale of wholesale electricity.Capacity payments typically involve a dollar per kilowatt year($/kW-year)payment to individual generation units based on some measure of the amount of their ca

227、pacity that is available to produce electricity during stressed system conditions,what is often referred to as the units“firm capacity.”For example,a base load coal-fired unit would have a firm capacity value very close to its nameplate capacity.Usually,the firm capacity of a thermal unit is equal t

228、o the units capacity in MWs times its availability factor.6 In hydroelectric-dominated markets,determining the firm capacity of a generation unit is an extremely challenging task.The firm capacity of a hydroelectric generation unit owner is typically based on the amount of energy the unit is capable

229、 of providing under the worst possible 6 Thermal generation units convert heat energy into electricity.These include coal-fired,natural gas-fired,oil-fired,nuclear,and geothermal.25 hydrological conditions.However,it is difficult,if not impossible,to determine the maximum amount of capacity or energ

230、y a hydroelectric unit can provide under these conditions,so there is a significant degree of arbitrariness in setting hydroelectric units firm capacity value.Second,because every hydroelectric unit owner would like a larger capacity value for their generation unit,in order to avoid accusations of a

231、rbitrary firm capacity values for individual generation units,the entity making this decision typically bases the figure on the amount of energy the unit produced during the historically worst hydrological conditions even though the system operator may have sound reasons for believing that this firm

232、 capacity value is set too high.As consequence,particularly in Latin America,there are numerous examples of capacity payment mechanisms that failed to ensure an adequate supply of energy and rationing conditions have been declared.Virtually all of the restructured markets in Latin America that have

233、capacity payment mechanismsspecifically,Brazil,Chile,and Colombiahave experienced supply shortfalls that have required rationing.McRae and Wolak(2019)present an analysis of the most recent supply shortfall period in Colombia and conclude that the perverse incentives created by the capacity payment m

234、echanism there was a major contributing factor to this outcome.Wind and solar generation units have a firm capacity values significantly below their nameplate capacity,but substantially more than the amount of energy these units are able to produce during stressed system conditions,which suggests th

235、at the capacity market construct is poorly suited to an electricity supply industry with significant intermittent renewable generation capacity.For example,on an extremely hot night solar generation units are not likely to produce any energy or on a hot sunny day,very little wind energy will be prod

236、uced.Consequently,the process of computing the firm capacity values for wind and solar units involves a significant number of unverifiable assumptions often aimed at increasing the resulting firm capacity values.Capacity payment mechanisms differ along a number of dimensions.In some regions,the paym

237、ent is made to all generation unit owners regardless of how much total generation capacity is needed to operate the system.In other regions,the independent system operator(ISO)specifies a system-wide demand for capacity equal to peak system demand plus some planning reserve,typically between 15 to 2

238、0 percent,and only makes capacity payments to enough generation units to meet this demand.There have been attempts to use market mechanisms to set the value of the$/kW-year payment to the generation units needed to meet the total demand for capacity.However,these capacity markets have been subject t

239、o almost continuous revision because they are extremely 26 susceptible to the exercise of unilateral market power.The nature of the product soldinstalled generation capacityand a publicly disclosed perfectly inelastic demand for the product creates extreme opportunities for suppliers to exercise uni

240、lateral market.In early versions of eastern US capacity markets,there were instances of the exercise of enormous amounts of unilateral market power.During the off-peak months of the year when no single supplier is pivotal in the capacity market,the price of paid for capacity was very close to zero,w

241、hich is the marginal cost of a supplier providing an additional MW of available capacity from existing generation capacity.7 During the peak and shoulder months when one or more suppliers are pivotal in the capacity market,there was no limit on the price a supplier could charge.This market power pro

242、blem leaves open the question of how to set the value of the$/kW-year price cap on the capacity payment.In all regions of the US with capacity payment mechanisms,there is an administratively set process for determining this price.The value of the maximum capacity payment is based on the regulators e

243、stimate of annual$/kW fixed cost of a peaking generation unit.This maximum price is typically backed by the argument that because of the offer cap on the short-term market and other market power mitigation mechanisms this peaking unit could only set an energy price slightly higher than its variable

244、operating costs.Because this generation unit and all other generation units are missing the hours when the market price would rise above their variable operating costs,the annual$/kW cost of the peaking unit is needed to compensate all generation units for the revenues they do not receive because of

245、 the offer cap and market power mitigation mechanisms.This logic for setting this value of$/kW-year capacity payment explicitly assumes that the real-time demand for electricity is completely price inelastic and that suppliers are unable to exercise significant amounts of unilateral market power in

246、the short-term market.Both of these assumptions are clearly false.An increasing number of jurisdictions around the world are installing hourly meters that allow dynamic pricing plans to be implemented.Wolak(2013)discusses these technologies and the pricing plans they enable.Wolfram(1999)applies a st

247、ructural model of imperfect competition to measure the extent of unilateral market power exercised in the early England and Wales electricity market.Patrick and Wolak(2001)document the strategic use of market rules to raise prices by two large generation 7 A supplier is said to be pivotal in a marke

248、t with an inelastic demand if some of their supply is needed to meet this demand regardless of the offers of other market participants.27 unit owners in this same electricity market.Wolak(2003a)documents changes in the unilateral ability of the five largest generation unit owners in the California e

249、lectricity market to exercise unilateral market power from 1998 to 2000.Borenstein,Bushnell and Wolak(2002)document the magnitude of the rent transfers and economic inefficiencies caused by these actions.McRae and Wolak(2012)demonstrate that the four largest generation unit owners in New Zealand app

250、ear to exercise unilateral market power,which is equivalent to a privately-owned firm serving its fiduciary duty to its shareholders or a publicly-owned firm serving its fiduciary responsibility to its ratepayers.All of these studies imply that despite the best efforts of regulators,it is highly unl

251、ikely that any market power mitigation mechanism could prevent the exercise of all unilateral market power.Capacity payment mechanisms make it extremely difficult for consumers to benefit from electricity industry restructuring relative to market without a capacity payment mechanism and active deman

252、d-side participation in the wholesale market.Recall that the capacity payment is made to either all generation units in the system or all generation units needed to meet the ISOs demand for capacity.On top of this,all generation unit owners typically receive the same market-clearing price for capaci

253、ty.Thus,to the extent that producers are able to exercise unilateral market power in the short-term energy market,they can raise energy prices significantly above the variable cost of the highest cost unit operating within the hour for all hours of the year,on top of receiving a capacity payment set

254、 by the highest offer price needed to meet the system demand for capacity.As noted above,capacity payment mechanisms are typically accompanied by offer caps on the short-term energy market that significantly limit the incentive for final consumers to become active participants in the short-term whol

255、esale market.For example,if the maximum wholesale price in an hour is$250/MWh because of an offer cap at this level,then a 1 KWh reduction in demand for a residential customer(a very large demand reduction)during an hour only saves the customer 25 cents,which is likely to be insufficient to cause th

256、at consumer to reduce its demand.This lack of an active demand-side in the wholesale market impacts how generation unit owners offer their units into the market,because all producers know that system demand will be the same regardless of the hourly wholesale price.Active participation by final deman

257、d substantially increases the competitiveness of the short-term wholesale market because all producers know that higher offer prices will result in less of their generation capacity being called upon to produce because the offers of final consumers to reduce their demand are accepted instead.Without

258、 an active demand-side of the wholesale market,28 generation unit owners know that they can submit offers that are farther above their variable cost of supplying electricity and not have these offers rejected.Consequently,a market with a capacity payment mechanism can charge consumers for the$/kW-ye

259、ar fixed cost of a peaker unit for their entire capacity needs and then give producers greater opportunities to exercise unilateral market power in the short-term market,which clearly reduces the likelihood that consumers will realize economic benefits from electricity restructuring.Another argument

260、 given for capacity payments is that they reduce the likelihood of long-term capacity inadequacy problems because of the promise of a capacity payment provides incentives for new generation units to enter the market.However,until very recently,in most markets around the world,capacity payments were

261、only promised for at most a single year and only paid to existing generation units.Both of these features substantially dulled the incentive for new generation units to enter the market,because a generation unit that entered the market only had a guarantee of receiving the capacity payment for one y

262、ear and no guarantee that if it received the payment the first year the unit owner would continue to receive it.This led the eastern US wholesale markets to develop of a long-term capacity product that is sold two to three years in advance of delivery to provide a sufficient lead-time for new genera

263、tion units to participate and capacity payments beyond a single year.This is a positive development for capacity markets,but it also raises the question of why not simply transition to a forward energy purchase requirement,rather than a forward capacity requirement given that most consumers do not w

264、ant more generation capacity built,but they do want their future energy needs met.Capacity markets are also poorly suited to regions with a significant share of intermittent renewables.In these markets it is rarely,if ever,the case that there is a capacity shortfall in the sense that there is insuff

265、icient installed generation capacity to meet peak demand.The more common problem is insufficient energy,typically in the form water stored behind a dam,to meet anticipated demand.With wind and solar photovoltaic generation units,capacity shortfalls are also extremely unlikely.It is more likely that

266、the sun does not shine or the wind does not blow for a sustained period of time.In both of these cases,the problem is not a capacity shortfall,but an energy shortfall.Consequently,a capacity payment mechanism that focuses on ensuring adequate installed capacity is unlikely to deliver the most cost-e

267、ffective solution for consumers to the problem of long-term energy adequacy in regions with a significant amount of intermittent renewable resources.29 The argument for a capacity market is strongest in a region with all dispatchable thermal generation units and no potential for active participation

268、 of final consumers in the wholesale market,particularly if the capacity procurement decision is done far enough in advance of delivery and for a long enough period of time to support new investment.The similarity between this solution and the long-term energy contracting solution argues in favor of

269、 the long-term contract for energy solution to the long-term resource adequacy problem.Galetovic,Munoz and Wolak(2015)use the example of the Chilean market design to demonstrate the market efficiency improvements from transitioning from a capacity payment-based market to an energy-contracting based

270、market.5.3.TheRoleofaLiquidForwardMarketforEnergyThe previous two subsections emphasize that short-term energy and capacity markets are extremely susceptible to the exercise of unilateral market power and the key to long-term resource adequacy at reasonable price is purchasing sufficient energy or c

271、apacity far enough in advance of delivery by electricity retailers and large customers for new entrants to compete with existing generation unit owners to provide the product.Signing a fixed-price forward contract for energy or capacity a day,month,or even a year ahead of delivery limits the number

272、of firms and technologies that are able to provide this energy.For example,a contract negotiated one day in advance limits the sources of supply to existing generation unit owners able to produce energy the following day.Even a year in advance limits the sources that can compete with existing genera

273、tion unit owners,because it takes longer than eighteen months to site and build a substantial new generation unit in virtually all wholesale electricity markets.To obtain the most competitive prices,at a minimum,the vast majority of the fixed-price forward contracts should be negotiated far enough i

274、n advance of delivery to allow new entrants to compete with existing generation unit owners.This logic argues for regulatory intervention to internalize the reliability externality through a long-term resource adequacy process that ensures a liquid forward market for energy or capacity for delivery

275、2 to 3 years into the future.If a liquid forward market for energy exists at this time horizon to delivery and there is adequate demand for energy at this delivery horizon,a restructured market will achieve long-term resource adequacy.A liquid forward market at the 2 to 3 year delivery horizon impli

276、es less need for regulatory intervention into shorter term forward markets.The regulator can raise the offer cap on the short-term market and this will stimulate the 30 demand for retailers and large consumers to hedge for their wholesale energy purchases at delivery horizons less than 2 years into

277、the future.By purchasing a hedge against the short-term price risk at the locations in the network where the retailer or large consumer withdraws energy,the buyer can rely on the financial incentives that the seller of the contracts faces to procure or produce this energy at the lowest possible cost

278、.Focusing the long-term resource adequacy process on the construction of generation units misses the important point that there is an increasing number of ways for markets to achieve long-term resource adequacy besides building generation units.For example,by the appropriate choice of the mix of gen

279、eration units,the same pattern of hourly demands throughout the year can be met with less total generation capacity and that can also cost electricity consumers less on an annual basis.Distributed generation and storage investments,active demand-side participation in the wholesale market can also al

280、low the same number of customers to be served with less grid-connected generation capacity.It is important to emphasize that most capacity markets do little to limit the ability or incentive of generation unit owners to exercise unilateral market power in the short-term energy market.Capacity paymen

281、t mechanisms typically have the requirement that the generation unit owner must offer their capacity into the short-term market at or below the offer cap on the short-term energy market.This requirement does little to limit the ability or incentive of generation unit owners to raise short-term price

282、s by exploiting the distribution of residual demand curves they face,as long as the resulting short-term prices are below the offer cap.Even in capacity markets with a scarcity payment refunds,the capacity payment mechanism does not limit the ability or incentive of producers to exercise unilateral

283、market power below the scarcity price.8 This is different from the case that a producer has a fixed-price forward contract obligation to supply energy,which endows the producer with strong incentive to reduce the cost of meeting this forward contract obligation for energy.Another advantage of focusi

284、ng on the development of a liquid forward market for energy instead of capacity is that an active forward market for energy has other hedging instruments besides so-called“swap contracts”where a generation unit owner and a retailer agree to a fixed price at a location in the transmission network for

285、 a fixed quantity of energy.Cap contracts are 8 A scarcity price refund requires the seller of firm capacity to pay max(0,P(market)P(scarcity)*QFirm,where P(market)is the market price,P(scarcity)is an administratively set scarcity price,and QFirm is the firm energy sold by the supplier.31 also very

286、effective instruments for guarding against price spikes in the short-term market and for funding for peaking generation capacity.For example,a generation unit owner might sell a retailer a cap contract that says that if the short-term price at a specific location exceeds the cap contract exercise pr

287、ice,the seller of the contract pays the buyer of the contract the difference between the spot price and the cap exercise price times the number of MWh of the cap contract sold.For example,suppose the cap exercise price is$300/MWh and market price is$400/MWh,then the payoff to the buyer from the cap

288、contract is$100/MWh=$400/MWh$300/MWh times the number of MWh sold.If the spot price is less than$300/MWh,then the buyer of the cap contract does not receive a payment.Because the seller of a cap contract is providing insurance against price spikes,it must make payments when the price exceeds the cap

289、 exercise price.This price spike insurance obligation implies that the buyer must make a fixed up-front payment to the seller in order for the seller to be willing to take on this obligation.This up-front payment can then be used by the seller of the cap contract to pay for a peaking generation unit

290、 that provides a physical hedge against price spikes at this location.The Australian electricity market has an active financial forward market where these types of cap contracts are traded and these contracts have been used to fund peaking generation capacity to provide the seller of the cap contrac

291、t with a physical hedge against this insurance obligation.Cross-hedging between generation resource owners is likely to become even more important to ensuring long-term resource adequacy in industries with significant amounts of wind and solar resources.A wind or solar resource owner that sells fixe

292、d-price and fixed-quantity forward contract for energy to a retailer is going to need to reinsure the quantity risk associated with such a contract.The wind or solar resource owner can sign a contract with a thermal resource owner that provides insurance against the quantity risk it faces from selli

293、ng a fixed-price and fixed-quantity contract.For example,the wind resource owner could purchase a cap contract for the quantity of energy sold in the fixed-price,fixed quantity contract to the retailer at a certain strike price and in this way have insurance against having the purchase energy from t

294、he short-term market at an extremely high price when the wind or solar resource is not producing energy.The up-front payment to the thermal resource for the price spike insurance would help to finance the fixed costs of thermal resource that operates significantly less frequently because of the larg

295、e amount of intermittent renewable generation capacity.The wind or solar resource owner would 32 then factor in the cost of this quantity risk insurance in the price it is willing to sell any fixed-price,fixed quantity forward contract for energy.One question often asked about an approach that focus

296、es on the development of an active forward market for energy is whether sufficient generation resources will be built to meet demand if consumers only buy forward financial hedges against the spot price at their location in the network.On this point,it is important to bear in mind the incentives fac

297、ed by a seller of the forward financial contract once this contract has been sold.The generation unit owner maximizes expected profits by ensuring that the forward contract quantity of energy can be purchased at the agreed-upon location in the spot market(or whatever market the forward contract clea

298、rs against)at the lowest possible short-term price.The seller of the contract bears all of the risk associated with higher spot prices at that location.In order to prudently hedge this risk,the seller has a very strong incentive to ensure that sufficient generation capacity is available to set the l

299、owest possible price in the short-term market at that location in the network for the quantity of energy sold in the fixed-price forward contract.This logic implies that if a generation unit owner signs a forward contract guaranteeing the price for 500 MWh of energy for 24 hours a day and 7 days per

300、 week at a specific location in the network,it will construct or contract for more than 500 MW of generation capacity to hedge this short-term price risk.Building only a 500 MW facility to hedge this risk would be extremely imprudent and expose the producer to significant risk,because if this 500 MW

301、 facility is unavailable to provide electricity,the producer must purchase the energy from the short-term market at the price that prevails at the time.Moreover,if this generation unit is unavailable,then the short-term price is likely to be extremely high.An addition source of economic benefits fro

302、m the energy-based resource adequacy process is that the energy contract adequacy approach does not require the regulator to set the total amount of firm capacity needed to meet system demand.Instead the regulator only ensures that retailers and large customers have adequate fixed-price forward cont

303、ract coverage of their demand at various delivery horizons into the future and then relies on the incentives that the sellers of these contracts face to construct sufficient generation capacity or procure other resources to meet these forward contract obligations for energy.The sellers of these forw

304、ard contracts for energy have a strong incentive to find the least-cost mix of generation and demand-side resources necessary to meet their contractual obligations.33 6.ManagingandMitigatingSystemwideandLocalMarketPowerThe configuration of the transmission network,the level and location of demand,as

305、 well as the level of output of other generation units can endow certain generation units with a significant ability to exercise unilateral market power in a wholesale market.A prime example of this phenomenon is the constrained-on generation problem described earlier.The owner of a constrained-on g

306、eneration unit knows that regardless of the units offer price,it must be accepted to supply energy.Without a local market power mitigation mechanism,there is no limit to what offer price that generation unit owner could submit and be accepted to provide energy.The system-wide market power problem is

307、 typically addressed through sufficient fixed-price and fixed-quantity long term contracts between producer and electricity retailers and large consumers.The logic of Wolak(2000)described in Section 5.1 demonstrates how fixed-price,fixed-quantity forward contracts limits the incentives of generation

308、 unit owners to exercise system-wide unilateral market power in the short-term market.6.1.SolutionstotheLocalMarketPowerProblemIn an offer-based market,the regulator must design and implement an automatic local market power mitigation mechanism that is built into the market mechanism.In general,the

309、regulator must determine when any type of market outcome causes enough harm to some market participants to merit explicit regulatory intervention.Finally,if the market outcomes become too harmful,the regulator must have the ability to temporarily suspend market operations.All of these tasks require

310、a substantial amount of subjective judgment on the part of the regulatory process,which can be extremely challenging for countries and regions with limited regulatory experience.In all offer-based electricity markets,a local market power mitigation(LMPM)mechanism is necessary to limit the offers a g

311、eneration unit owner submits when it faces is insufficient competition to serve a local energy need because of combination of the configuration of the transmission network,the levels and geographic distribution of demands,and the concentration of ownership of generation units.One lesson from the exp

312、erience of US markets(in particular)is that system conditions can arise when virtually any generation unit owner has a substantial ability and incentive to exercise unilateral market power.That is why prospective market power mitigation mechanisms where certain units are designated in advance as hav

313、ing the ability to exercise unilateral market power that are typically used in Europe and other industrialized 34 countries and initially employed in the US are likely to miss many instances of the exercise of substantial unilateral market power.A LMPM mechanism built into the market software that r

314、elies on actual system conditions to determine whether a generation unit has a substantial ability and incentive to exercise unilateral is likely to be significantly more effective.This logic explains why all US markets currently have such a mechanism built into their market software and runs automa

315、tically each pricing interval.A LMPM mechanism is a pre-specified administrative procedure(written into the market rules)that determines:(1)when a producer has local market power worthy of mitigation,(2)what the mitigated producer will be paid,and(3)how the amount the producer is paid will impact th

316、e payments received by other market participants.Without a prospective market power mitigation mechanism system conditions are likely to arise in all wholesale markets when almost any generation unit owner can exercise substantial unilateral market power.It is increasingly clear to regulators around

317、 the world,particularly those that operate markets with limited amounts of transmission capacity,these automatic regulatory interventions are necessary to deal with the problem of insufficient competition to serve certain local energy needs.An important component of any local and system-wide market

318、power mitigation mechanism is the provision of information to market participants and public at large.This is often termed,“smart sunshine regulation.”This means that the regulatory process gathers a comprehensive set of information about market outcomes,analyzes it,and make it available to the publ

319、ic in a manner and form that increases the likelihood of market participant compliance with all market rules and allows the regulatory and political process to detect and correct market design flaws in a timely manner.Smart sunshine regulation is the foundation for all of the tasks the regulatory pr

320、ocess must undertake in the wholesale market regime.Wolak(2014)discusses the benefits of smart sunshine regulation and public data release on wholesale market performance.Another tool a regulator has in managing local and system-wide market power in an offer-based market is determining the configura

321、tion of the transmission network.Because the configuration of the transmission network can often determine the extent of competition that individual generation unit owners face,the regulator must take a more active role in the transmission planning and expansion process to ensure that competition-en

322、hancing upgrades that improve market efficiency are built.Wolak(2019)described the distinctly different roles of transmission network planning in the vertically-integrated monopoly regime versus the wholesale market regime.Wolak(2015)presents a framework for measuring the competitiveness benefits 35

323、 of transmission expansions in an offer-based wholesale market and applies it to the Alberta,Canada wholesale electricity market.6.2.CostBasedShortTermMarket An alternative approach that is used in a number of Latin American markets is a cost-based market.Under this mechanism generation unit owners

324、do not submit offers to the market operator.Instead the market operator takes the technical characteristics of generation units and input fuel prices to compute the variable cost of operating each generation unit.These variable cost estimates are used by the market operator to dispatch generation un

325、its and set market prices.This mechanism avoids the need for a local market power mitigation mechanism,but is not without its challenges.For example,it does not completely close off opportunities for generation unit owners to exercise unilateral market power because they can still withhold their out

326、put from the cost-based dispatch as a way to increase short-term prices.They can also take actions to raise their regulated variable cost that enters the cost-based dispatch process.Wolak(2014)discusses the market efficiency trade-offs between offer-based versus cost-based markets.6.3.SolutionstoSys

327、temWideMarketPowerAs discussed in Section 5 and in detail in Wolak(2000),fixed-price forward contract commitments sold by generation unit owners reduce their incentive to exercise unilateral market power in the short-term energy market because the generation unit owner only earns the short-term pric

328、e on any energy it sells in excess of its forward contract commitment and pays the short-term price for any production shortfall relative to these forward contract commitments.This logic argues in favor of the regulator monitoring the forward contract positions of retailers as part of its regulatory

329、 oversight process to ensure that there is adequate fixed-price forward contract coverage of final demand.As discussed in Wolak(2003b)and reinforced by the simulation results of Bushnell,Mansur and Saravia(2008),the California electricity crisis is very unlikely to have occurred if there had been ad

330、equate coverage of Californias retail electricity demand with fixed-price and fixed-quantity forward contracts.Consequently,in order to protect against periods when one or more generation unit owners has a strong incentive to exercise unilateral market power,the regulator should,at a minimum,monitor

331、 the forward contracting levels of the retailers they oversee as the primary mechanism to protect against the exercise of system-wide unilateral market power.36 7.ActiveInvolvementofFinalDemandintheWholesaleMarketThe active involvement of final consumers in the wholesale market can reduce the amount

332、 of installed generation capacity needed to serve them and can reduce the cost of integrating an increasing amount of intermittent renewable generation.An important market design feature that facilitates active participation by final demand is a multi-settlement market with a day-ahead forward marke

333、t and real-time market.This mechanism allows loads to purchase energy in the day-ahead market that they can subsequently sell in the real-time market.Without the ability to purchase demand in the day-ahead market that is not consumed in real-time,demand reduction programs require the regulator to set an administrative baseline relative to which demand reductions are measured,which can significantl

友情提示

1、下载报告失败解决办法
2、PDF文件下载后,可能会被浏览器默认打开,此种情况可以点击浏览器菜单,保存网页到桌面,就可以正常下载了。
3、本站不支持迅雷下载,请使用电脑自带的IE浏览器,或者360浏览器、谷歌浏览器下载即可。
4、本站报告下载后的文档和图纸-无水印,预览文档经过压缩,下载后原文更清晰。

本文(世界银行:批发电力市场设计:理论基础与选择(英文版)(53页).pdf)为本站 (Kelly Street) 主动上传,三个皮匠报告文库仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。 若此文所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知三个皮匠报告文库(点击联系客服),我们立即给予删除!

温馨提示:如果因为网速或其他原因下载失败请重新下载,重复下载不扣分。
客服
商务合作
小程序
服务号
会员动态
会员动态 会员动态:

wei**n_...  升级为标准VIP  139**98... 升级为至尊VIP 

152**90...  升级为标准VIP  138**98... 升级为标准VIP

 181**96... 升级为标准VIP  185**10... 升级为标准VIP

wei**n_...  升级为至尊VIP 高兴 升级为至尊VIP 

wei**n_... 升级为高级VIP  wei**n_...  升级为高级VIP 

  阿**... 升级为标准VIP wei**n_...  升级为高级VIP

 lin**fe... 升级为高级VIP wei**n_... 升级为标准VIP

 wei**n_...  升级为高级VIP wei**n_... 升级为标准VIP 

wei**n_...  升级为高级VIP  wei**n_... 升级为高级VIP

wei**n_... 升级为至尊VIP  wei**n_... 升级为高级VIP 

wei**n_...  升级为高级VIP  180**21...   升级为标准VIP

183**36...  升级为标准VIP  wei**n_...  升级为标准VIP

wei**n_...  升级为标准VIP xie**.g... 升级为至尊VIP 

 王** 升级为标准VIP 172**75... 升级为标准VIP 

wei**n_...  升级为标准VIP  wei**n_... 升级为标准VIP

 wei**n_... 升级为高级VIP 135**82... 升级为至尊VIP 

130**18...  升级为至尊VIP wei**n_...  升级为标准VIP

wei**n_...  升级为至尊VIP  wei**n_...  升级为高级VIP

130**88... 升级为标准VIP  张川 升级为标准VIP 

 wei**n_... 升级为高级VIP  叶** 升级为标准VIP

wei**n_...  升级为高级VIP    138**78... 升级为标准VIP

wu**i   升级为高级VIP wei**n_...  升级为高级VIP

wei**n_... 升级为标准VIP  wei**n_...   升级为高级VIP

185**35... 升级为至尊VIP  wei**n_...  升级为标准VIP

 186**30... 升级为至尊VIP  156**61... 升级为高级VIP

130**32... 升级为高级VIP   136**02... 升级为标准VIP

 wei**n_... 升级为标准VIP   133**46... 升级为至尊VIP

wei**n_... 升级为高级VIP  180**01...  升级为高级VIP

 130**31... 升级为至尊VIP  wei**n_... 升级为至尊VIP

微**...  升级为至尊VIP  wei**n_...  升级为高级VIP

wei**n_...  升级为标准VIP  刘磊 升级为至尊VIP 

 wei**n_... 升级为高级VIP 班长  升级为至尊VIP

 wei**n_... 升级为标准VIP 176**40...   升级为高级VIP

136**01...  升级为高级VIP  159**10...  升级为高级VIP

君君**i...  升级为至尊VIP  wei**n_... 升级为高级VIP

wei**n_... 升级为标准VIP 158**78...  升级为至尊VIP 

微**...   升级为至尊VIP 185**94...  升级为至尊VIP 

wei**n_... 升级为高级VIP   139**90... 升级为标准VIP

 131**37...  升级为标准VIP  钟**  升级为至尊VIP

wei**n_...  升级为至尊VIP  139**46... 升级为标准VIP

 wei**n_... 升级为标准VIP wei**n_... 升级为高级VIP 

150**80...  升级为标准VIP wei**n_...  升级为标准VIP 

GT  升级为至尊VIP 186**25... 升级为标准VIP  

 wei**n_...  升级为至尊VIP  150**68... 升级为至尊VIP

 wei**n_...  升级为至尊VIP 130**05... 升级为标准VIP  

wei**n_... 升级为高级VIP  wei**n_... 升级为高级VIP  

wei**n_...  升级为高级VIP 138**96...  升级为标准VIP

135**48...  升级为至尊VIP  wei**n_... 升级为标准VIP

肖彦  升级为至尊VIP wei**n_...  升级为至尊VIP

 wei**n_... 升级为高级VIP wei**n_... 升级为至尊VIP